trade Reference Manual

Disclaimer: The views expressed herein are entirely those of the authors and should not be purported to reflect those of the Federal Trade Commission. The trade package has been released into the public domain without warranty of any kind, expressed or implied. We thank Ronald Drennan, Robert Majure, Russell Pittman, Gloria Sheu, Nathan Miller, Randy Chugh, Marc Remer, Alexander Raskovich, William Drake, Thomas Jeitschko, Greg Werden, Luke Froeb, Nicholas Hill, and Conor Ryan. Address: Bureau of Economics #202, Federal Trade Commission, 600 Pennsylvania Ave. NW, Washington, DC 20530. email:

Introduction

trade is a suite of tools that may be used in assessing the implications of tariffs. The package contains functions that can calibrate the underlying parameters of a number of different supply and demand models as well as simulate the effects of tariffs in different strategic environments. The output generated by these tools includes interesting features such as predicted price increases, welfare measures and demand elasticities.

There are four features of trade that make it particularly useful for practitioners. First, trade collects a number of useful models onto a common platform, making it easy for practitioners to compare and contrast the results from different models.

Second, trade is open source software that runs on the R open source platform. Practically speaking, this means that practitioners not only have the flexibility to run this software wherever and whenever they wish, but they can also modify and extend the software as they see fit. We hope that having this collection of tools on a common, open source platform will facilitate discussion and collaboration among practitioners.

Third, trade includes a web interface built using shiny. While this interface does not give users access to the full array of functionality in trade, it is simple to use and may provide first-time users, particularly those who are unfamiliar with R, a gentler introduction to trade. The interface may be invoked using the ct_shiny function in the competitiontoolbox package.

Finally, the functions included in trade typically require relatively little information to generate a prediction.

The limited information needed for the economic models used in trade comes at some cost. First, the output of these models is sensitive to the supplied inputs. For instance, when employing the Bertrand model, inaccurate margins, shares and prices can yield inaccurate estimates of demand and cost parameters which can in turn yield incorrect predictions of a tariff’s effects. Calibrating model parameters with an array of plausible inputs will yield a range of outputs and illustrate the sensitivity of each model to those inputs. One way to control for inaccurate inputs is to calibrate model parameters with different plausible inputs to see how the model output changes. Users can then report a range of plausible outputs in their analysis.

Moreover, none of the parameters calibrated by trade may be used in frequentist statistical hypothesis testing. In other words, while the economic models in trade may be used to generate reliable estimates of the effects of a new tariff regime, statistical tests cannot be used to determine the accuracy of these estimates. Accomplishing this requires additional data and is beyond the current scope of trade.

This document provides an introduction to the economic theory upon which the trade package’s functions are built. Please use the help function for assistance invoking any of the functions, classes, or methods included in trade. Alternatively, please refer to the vignette and manpages of trade’s sister package antitrust from which much of trade was generated.

The Bertrand Pricing Game

Much of trade‘s functionality is built around the Bertrand pricing game.1 This version of the game assumes that firms producing multiple differentiated products with distinct, constant, marginal costs simultaneously set their products’ prices to maximize their profits. In this model, prices are strategic complements in the sense that increasing the price of one product causes some customers to switch to other products, raising the quantities sold and therefore the profit-maximizing prices of these other products. Ultimately, it is the magnitude of these lost sales that, at the margin, dissuades firms from raising their prices further.

Tariffs are modeled by effectively assuming that the marginal costs of certain products produced by foreign firms increase by the amount of the tariff. Because all products included in trade models are assumed to be substitutes, this marginal cost increase causes foreign firms to raise the price of their products, which in turn causes some customers to either switch to other products in the market or to forgo purchasing any product in the market entirely.

The Bertrand model predicts that tariffs will harm customers and foreign firms, but benefit domestic firms and raise government revenues. The magnitude of these effects, however, will depend on demand specification as well as the set of inputs used.2

Currently, this version of the Bertrand model does not allow firms to add or reposition products, or allow firms to engage in some forms of price discrimination.

The primary trade function responsible for modeling tariffs in a Bertrand game is bertrand_tariff.

The Game

Suppose that there are K firms in a market, and that each of the k ∈ K firms produces nk products, some of which may be produced domestically and some of which may be produced abroad.3 Further, suppose that the government imposes an ad valorem tariff ti on a subset of products produced abroad. Note that we assume that the tariff is calculated as a proportion of consumer price, so that the price received by the firm is 1 − ti the price faced by consumers.

Let $n=\sum\limits_{k\in K}n_k$ denote the number of products sold by all K firms. The Bertrand model assumes that firms simultaneously set their products’ prices in order to maximize their profits. This model also assumes that all firms can perfectly observe each others’ prices, quantities, costs, and product characteristics.

This version of the Bertrand model also assumes that each product is produced using its own distinct constant marginal cost technology ci, for all i ∈ n. As we will see, this assumption is necessary when information is limited.

Firm k ∈ K chooses the prices {pi}i = 1nk of its products so as to maximize profits. Mathematically, firm k solves:

where ti equals 0 if the product is not subject to a tariff. qi, the quantity sold of product i, is assumed to be a twice differentiable function of all product prices.

Differentiating profits with respect to each pi yields the following first order conditions (FOCs):

which may be rewritten as

where $r_i\equiv\frac{p_iq_i}{\sum\limits_{j=1}^np_jq_j}$ is product i’s revenue share, $\hat{c}_i\equiv \frac{c_i}{(1-t_i)}$ is product i’s effective marginal cost, $m_i\equiv\frac{p_i-\hat{c}_i}{p_i}$ is product i’s gross margin, and $\epsilon_{ij}\equiv\frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_j}\frac{p_j}{q_i}$ is the elasticity of product i with respect to the price of product j.

The FOCs for all products may be stacked and then represented using the following matrix notation:

where r and m are n-length vectors of revenue shares and margins, $E = \left(\begin{smallmatrix} \epsilon_{11}&\ldots&\epsilon_{1n}\\\vdots &\ddots&\vdots\\\epsilon_{n1}&\ldots&\epsilon_{nn} \end{smallmatrix}\right)$ is a n × n matrix of own- and cross-price elasticities, and $\Omega=\left(\begin{smallmatrix} \omega_{11}(1-t_1)&\ldots&\omega_{1n}(1-t_1)\\\vdots &\ddots&\vdots\\\omega_{n1}(1-t_n)&\ldots&\omega_{nn}(1-t_n)\end{smallmatrix}\right)$ is an n × n matrix whose i, jth element equals ωij, the share of product j’s profits owned by the firm setting product i’s price, multiplied by 1 − ti, product i’s tariff rate. In many cases, product i and j are wholly owned by a single firm, in which cases ωij equals 1 if i and j are owned by the same firm and 0 otherwise. ‘diag’ returns the diagonal of a square matrix and ‘’ is the Hadamard (entry-wise) product operator.

The solution to system @ref(eq:FOC) yields equilibrium prices conditional on the ownership structure Ω and tariffs ti, ∀i ∈ n. A change in tariff policy is modeled as the solution to system @ref(eq:FOC) where Ω and i, ∀i ∈ n are updated to reflect the change in tariffs.

Quotas

The Bertrand model described above assumes that products are produced with constant marginal costs and no quotas. Here, we extend this model to allow for quotas.4

Firm k ∈ K chooses the prices {pi}i = 1nk of its products so as to maximize profits, subject to quotas $\{\overline{q}_i\}_{i=1}^{n_k}$. Mathematically, firm k solves:

In general, either the capacity constraint for product i will bind and the firm will be forced to produce less of i than it would find optimal, or the capacity constraint will not bind, and the firm will produce the optimal amount implied by the FOCs. In the former, it can be shown that pi ≤ 0 and $q_i - \overline{q}_i=0$, while in the latter pi = 0 and $q_i - \overline{q}_i \le 0$. Mathematically, these cases can be written as

The FOCs for the quota-constrained Bertrand game (equation ) suffer from an additional complication: the function introduces a kink that can make it difficult for the non-linear equation solver to find equilibrium prices. Froeb, Tschantz, and Crooke (2003) suggests replacing equation @ref(eq:FOCC) with

which has the same roots as equation @ref(eq:FOCC), but is smoother. The method for all classes based on the capacity-constrained Bertrand Model use this smoothed system to solve for equilibrium prices when the constraint is binding.

Calibrating Model Demand and Cost Parameters

For the Logit, CES, and AIDS demand specifications allowed under this implementation of the Bertrand model, the calibration strategy is the same. First, we assume that quantities/shares and (with the exception of LA-AIDS) prices are observed for all products in the market, and that margins for some products are observed. Our decision to treat quantities, prices, and margins as primitives comes directly from equation @ref(eq:FOC).

In addition to quantities, prices, some margins and capacities, we assume that users observe diversion ratios. Diversion ratios come in two forms: quantity diversion and revenue diversion. The quantity diversion from product i to product j, dijq, is defined as the percentage of all of i’s lost unit sales that switch to j due to a price increase in product i, while the revenue diversion from product i to product j, dijr, is defined as the percentage of all of i’s lost revenue that switches to j due to a price increase in product i. Mathematically, quantity and revenue diversion may be represented as

Note that dijq, dijr are restricted to be between -1 and 1, and are positive if products i and j are substitutes and negative if they are complements. Additionally, conditional on customers switching from product i, they must switch to another product (i.e. jdij ≤ 0). For all the models included in trade, we assume that i and j are not complements (dij ≥ 0) and for some demand models (i.e. AIDS) we will assume that jdij = 0.

Although diversion ratios are not present in equation @ref(eq:FOC), these definitions indicate that diversion ratios may be helpful in recovering the matrix of own- and cross-price elasticities E. Indeed, for a number of the demand systems described below, diversions will be used for just this purpose.

We further assume that all of this information represents the outcome of the unique current equilibrium for firms in the market playing the static Bertrand pricing game described above. We then substitute observed margins, shares and prices into equation @ref(eq:FOC), which is now solely a function of demand parameters, and then solve for the coefficient(s) on prices. Once the price coefficients have been estimated, we use observed prices and the demand equations to estimate the intercepts.

Often, there are more FOCs than unknown price coefficients. For instance, under Logit demand, only the price parameter α and the share of the outside good s0 needs to be estimated and up to n FOCs with which to estimate it. This means that at a minimum, users need only supply enough margin information to complete a single product’s FOC. If that product happens to be owned by a single-product firm, then only one margin is necessary. On the other hand, if the product happens to be owned by a multi-product firm, then at a minimum, all the margins for products owned by that firm must be supplied.

The (Marshallian) demand specifications used in trade can be grouped into two categories: demand systems that are derived from a representative consumer’s expenditure function and demand systems that are derived from a representative consumer’s indirect utility function. The LA-AIDS demand system fall into the former category, while the Logit and CES fall into the latter category. Below, we briefly discuss these demand systems as well as the assumptions and/or data needed to recover estimates of the demand parameters.

We conclude this section with a discussion of how calibrated demand parameters and the FOCs can be used to calibrate product-specific constant marginal costs.

Logit Demand With Unobserved Outside Share

The Bertrand model with Logit demand and unobserved outside share may be implemented using the bertrand_tariff function with ‘demand’ equal to “logit”.

Logit demand is based on a discrete choice model that assumes that each consumer is willing to purchase at most a single unit of one product from the set of I products available in the market. When consumers choose not to purchase one of the products in the market, they are assumed to purchase the “outside good.”

This model assumes that while the quantities of the products included in the market can be observed with some accuracy, the quantity of all the products excluded from the market (i.e. the “outside good”) is difficult to estimate reliably. The bertrand_tariff function attempts to circumvent this issue by treating the share of the outside good as a nuisance parameter and using additional margin and/or aggregate elasticity information to estimate that parameter.5

The assumptions underlying Logit demand imply that the probability that a consumer purchases product i ∈ I is given by

where si|I is product i’s quantity share, conditional on a product being chosen from the set of inside goods I, and s0 is the share of the outside good. This implies that We assume that Vi takes on the following form

Likewise, the own, cross, and market price elasticities may be written as

where $\overline{p}$ is the quantity share-weighted average price of the inside goods.

This version of the Logit model has |I| + 2 parameters to estimate (|I| δs, α, and s0) and up to 2|I| + 1 equations with which to estimate them (up to |I| complete FOCs, |I| choice probabilities and the market elasticity equation). calcSlopes exploits this over-identification by employing a minimum distance algorithm to find the values for α and s0 that best satisfy all the equations for which there are data, subject to the constraints that α is negative and s0 is between 0 and 1. The δs are then recovered from the choice probabilities, while constant marginal costs are recovered from fitted current tariff margins and observed prices.

CES Demand With Unobserved Outside Share

The Bertrand model with Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) demand and unobserved outside share may be implemented using the bertrand_tariff function with ‘demand’ equal to “ces.”

Like the Logit, CES demand is based on a discrete choice model. However, CES differs from the Logit model in that under CES consumers do not purchase a single unit of a product but instead spend a fixed proportion of their budget on one of the I products available in the market or the outside option.6

The assumptions underlying CES demand imply that the probability that a consumer purchases product i ∈ I is given by

where ri|I is product i’s revenue share, conditional on a product being chosen from the set of inside goods I, r0 is the revenue share of the outside good, and Vi is the (average) indirect utility that a consumer receives from purchasing product i. We assume that Vi takes on the following form

The CES demand system yields the following own- and cross-price elasticities:

where $\overline{p}$ is the revenue share-weighted average price of the inside goods.

Functional form differences aside, one important difference between the CES and Logit demand systems is that the Logit model’s choice probabilities are based on quantity shares, while the CES model’s choice probabilities are based on revenue shares.

Like Logit demand, CES demand has |I| + 2 parameters to estimate (|I| δs, γ, and r0) and up to 2|I| + 1 equations with which to estimate them (up to |I| complete FOCs, |I| choice probabilities, and the market elasticity equation). ces exploits this over-identification by employing a minimum distance algorithm to find the values for γ and r0 that best satisfy all the equations for which there are data, subject to the constraints that γ is greater than 1 and r0 is between 0 and 1. The δs are then recovered from the choice probabilities, while constant marginal costs are recovered from fitted current tariff margins and observed prices.

LA-AIDS Demand

The Bertrand model with the linear approximate Almost Ideal Demand System (LA-AIDS) may be implemented using the bertrand_tariff function with ‘demand’ equal to “aids.”

The LA-AIDS without income effects assumes that the demand for each product i ∈ n in the market is given by

which may be written in matrix notation as

where r, p are vectors of product revenue shares and prices, α is a vector of product-specific demand intercepts and B is a matrix of slopes.7

The LA-AIDS model yields the following own- and cross-price elasticities:

where ϵ is the market elasticity of demand.

The LA-AIDS model assumes that B is symmetric, satisfies homogeneity of degree zero in prices, and that diversion is known. The LA-AIDS model, however, assumes that revenue diversion, rather than quantity diversion is observed.8 Under these two assumptions, there are $\frac{n(n+3)}{2}$ unknown demand parameters ($\frac{n(n-1)}{2}$ diagonal elements in B, n diagonal elements, and n intercepts) and up to n(n + 1) equations (n(n − 1) diversion equations, n FOCs and n demand equations), in which case the system is over-identified.9

Unlike the Logit and CES models described above, none of the LA-AIDS model’s equations are a function of the share of the outside good. Instead, these equations are a function of the market elasticity of demand ϵ. Roughly speaking, ϵ controls the extent to which consumers substitute to products outside the n products included in the simulation given a small change in market-wide product prices. Here, we assume that ϵ is a parameter whose value is not a function of product prices.10

The calcSlopes method, called by the aids function to calibrate the AIDS parameters, uses a minimum distance algorithm to find the ϵ (if not supplied using the ‘mktElast’ argument) and a single diagonal element of B that best satisfy i) all the FOCs for which there is sufficient information and ii) the diversion equations $d_{ij}=-\frac{\beta_{ji}}{\beta_{ii}}$, and iii) the market elasticity (if supplied using the ‘mktElast’ argument). The βii’s are recovered from the fact that jdij = 0; customers must switch to a product included in the model.

Another distinguishing feature of the LA-AIDS model is that it does not require any information on product prices in order to simulate tariff price effects. The LA-AIDS accomplishes this by using the supplied margin and revenue information to estimate B, but not α. There are, however, a few drawbacks to not using pricing information. First, while tariff-specific price changes may be calculated, pre- and post-tariff price levels cannot. Second, welfare measures like compensating variation cannot be calculated. Prices are an optional input to aids and pcaids, and when they are supplied both price levels and welfare measures may be calculated.

The Cournot Quantity Game

Another model included in trade is the Cournot quantity game. This version of the game assumes that multi-plant firms with distinct, increasing marginal costs producing multiple products simultaneously set plant output for each product to maximize their profits.11 All firms producing a particular product are assumed to be undifferentiated. In this model, quantities are strategic substitutes in the sense that decreasing the quantity of one product causes some customers to switch to competing manufacturers, raising their quantities and profits. Ultimately, it is the magnitude of these lost sales that, at the margin, dissuades firms from reducing their output further .

Similar to the Bertrand model, tariffs are modeled by effectively assuming that the marginal costs of certain products produced by foreign firms increase by the amount of the tariff. Because all plants included in trade models are assumed to be producing substitutes, this marginal cost increase causes foreign firms to restrict plant output, which in turn raises product price.

Because all firms are manufacturing an identical version of the product, this version of the Cournot model allows firms under the new tariff regime to start or stop producing other products. This model does not allow for firms to engage in some forms of price discrimination.12

The Game

Suppose that there are K firms in a market, each producing a subset Jk of J products. Further, suppose that that each of the k ∈ K firms manufactures its Jk products at nk plants. Let n = ∑k ∈ Knk denote the total number of plants producing any of the J products. The Cournot model assumes that firms simultaneously set the amount of each product produced at each plant in order to maximize their profits. This model also assumes that all firms can perfectly observe each others’ quantities, and costs, as well as the demand for each product. Further, suppose that the government imposes an ad valorem tariff ti on a subset of products produced at plants located abroad. Note that we assume that the tariff is calculated as a proportion of consumer price, so that the price received by the firm is 1 − ti the price faced by consumers.

Functions in trade’s Cournot model also adopt the additional assumption that each firm’s plant has its own distinct marginal cost technology.

Firm k ∈ K chooses product output at each plant $\{q_j^r\}_{\substack{j\in j_k,\\ r\in n_k}}$ so as to maximize profits. Mathematically, firm k solves:

subject to

where pj, the price sold of product j, is assumed to be a twice differentiable function of all firm quantities with $\frac{\partial p_j}{\partial q_j^r}< 0$ for all plants r and products j. Likewise, additively separable plant variable costs cr assumed to be twice differentiable with $\frac{\partial c^r}{\partial q_j^r}> 0$ . Finally, tjr is the tariff imposed on plant r producing product j.

Differentiating profits with respect to each qjr yields the following first order conditions (FOCs):

Calibrating Model Demand and Cost Parameters

The Cournot model can yield different equilibrium quantity and price predictions depending on 1) the curvature of plant variable costs and 2) the curvature of demand. trade allows users to explore the consequences of different cost and demand assumptions.

Currently, cournot contains two different ways to specify plant costs. First, users can set the ‘cost’ option equal to a n-length character vector whose values are either equal to “linear” for linear marginal costs ($\frac{\partial c^r}{\partial q_j^r}= 0.5\gamma_r\sum_{j\in n_r}q_j^r$) or “constant” for constant marginal costs ($\frac{\partial c^r}{\partial q_j^r}= \gamma_r$) . When the ‘cost’ option is employed, cournot’s calcSlopes method uses observed costs (implied by predicted margins and prices) and prices to calibrate plant-level cost parameters γr.

Alternatively, users can specify both plant-level marginal and variable costs. Marginal costs may be specified by setting the ‘mcfunPre’ argument equal to a length n list of functions that each take as an input the vector of product quantities produced at a plant and then return the marginal cost associated with producing that level of output at that plant. Likewise, the ‘vcfunPre’ argument can be similarly used to specify plant-level variable costs. Note that when marginal costs and variable costs are specified in this manner, cournot makes no attempt to calibrate any parameters on the cost side.

Currently, cournot allows users to specify that product demand is either linear (pj = bj + ajk ∈ nqjk) or log-linear (ln (pj) = bj + ajln (∑k ∈ nqjk)). Users can specify product demand by setting cournot‘s ’demand’ argument equal to a j-length character vector equal to either “linear” for linear demand or “log” for log-linear demand.

References

Anderson, Simon P., André de Palma, and Brent Kreider. 2001a. “Tax Incidence in Differentiated Product Oligopoly.” Journal of Public Economics 81 (2): 173–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00079-7.
———. 2001b. “The Efficiency of Indirect Taxes Under Imperfect Competition.” Journal of Public Economics 81 (2): 231–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00085-2.
Froeb, Luke, Steven Tschantz, and Philip Crooke. 2003. “Bertrand Competition with Capacity Constraints: Mergers Among Parking Lots.” Journal of Econometrics 113 (1): 49–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(02)00166-5.
Werden, Gregory J, and Luke M Froeb. 1994. “The Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 10 (2): 407–26. https://ideas.repec.org/a/oup/jleorg/v10y1994i2p407-26.html.

  1. trade’s version of the Bertrand pricing game extends Werden and Froeb (1994) and Anderson, Palma, and Kreider (2001a) to accommodate tariffs under Bertrand price competition.↩︎

  2. Specifically, the curvature of the demand curve greatly influences the results.↩︎

  3. Throughout, we abuse the notation slightly by treating variables like K as both the set of firms as well as the number of firms.↩︎

  4. This section is based on the model described in Froeb, Tschantz, and Crooke (2003).↩︎

  5. The outside good is a nuisance parameter because it is only needed to obtain estimates of the other demand and cost parameters and is not used to solve for equilibrium prices.↩︎

  6. Formally, each consumer chooses the product i ∈ I that yields the maximum utility Ui = ln (δiqi) + αln (q0) + ϵi, subject to the budget constraint y = piqi + q0. Here, qi is the amount of product i consumed by a consumer, δi is a measure of product i’s quality, q0 is the amount of the numeraire, y is consumer income, and ϵi are random variables independently and identically distributed according to the Type I Extreme Value distribution.↩︎

  7. LA-AIDS differs from AIDS in that LA-AIDS substitutes the AIDS price index with Stone’s price index. Since this version of LA-AIDS is without income effects, Stone’s price index is only used to derive the own- and cross-price elasticities.↩︎

  8. If the ‘diversion’ argument to bertrand_tariff is missing, bertrand_tariff assumes diversion according to revenue share.↩︎

  9. In fact, it turns out that only one element of B must be estimated.To see why, note that under symmetry, $\beta_{jj}=\frac{d_{ij}}{d_{ji}}\beta_{ii}$. Hence, if βii is known, then the preceding equation indicates that all the βjjs may be recovered. From here, the definition of diversion may be used to recover all the βijs.↩︎

  10. This assumption implies that customers substitute to products outside of the simulation in response to price increases by all products in the simulation at the same rate before and after the change in tariffs.↩︎

  11. trade’s version of the Cournot quantity game extends (Anderson, Palma, and Kreider 2001b) to accommodate tariffs under Cournot quantity competition.↩︎

  12. In particular, this version of the Bertrand model does not accommodate non-linear pricing, such as is used in 2nd or 3rd degree price discrimination.↩︎